A Brief Colonial History Of Ceylon(SriLanka)
Sri Lanka: One Island Two Nations
A Brief Colonial History Of Ceylon(SriLanka)
Sri Lanka: One Island Two Nations
(Full Story)
Search This Blog
Back to 500BC.
==========================
Thiranjala Weerasinghe sj.- One Island Two Nations
?????????????????????????????????????????????????Wednesday, May 1, 2013
Caste, Religion And Fragmented Societies
By Latika Chaudhary -
Read
more – LSE
blog
*Latika Chaudhary is an Assistant Professor of
Economics at Scripps College. She recently delivered the2013 Epstein Lecture at LSE’s Department of
Economic History.
Caste, religion and fragmented societies: Education in British India
Latika
Chaudhary explores how colonial policies interacted with local conditions to
influence the trajectory of Indian education. This is the second of two blogs on
public goods provisions in colonial India.
The
subject of education and human capital is among the most neglected in Indian
economic history, even though recent decades have clearly established the
importance of education to economic growth and development. An educated labour
force has been linked to greater worker productivity, a faster ability to adopt
new technologies and lower crime. Understanding the economics of India’s
schooling record is important in and of itself, and also because it can inform
debates surrounding the Indian economy under the Raj. This post uses
quantitative data and examines specific factors that hurt the expansion of mass
education in the late nineteenth and twentieth century in India.
Despite
various political changes – including the decentralisation of education to
provincial governments, and the transfer of education oversight to provincial
legislative councils composed of elected Indian representatives – enrolment and
literacy rates remained stable and disappointingly low for most of the colonial
period. Total enrolment as a percentage of the population from 1850 to 1940
illustrates a picture of steady progress; that said, the increase is not
particularly significant because India moved from an extremely low level of
0.014 per cent in 1853 to four per cent in 1940, which was still a low
level.
The
aggregate enrollment patterns provide strong evidence of India’s limited
achievement at the primary level, but relatively superior performance at the
secondary level. As late as 1891 only one out of 10 primary school-age children
were enrolled in any type of school. The number of students enrolled steadily
increased in the twentieth century, but even by 1941 only one-third of school
age children (35 per cent) were enrolled in school, with sharp regional
differences. Secondary and collegiate level enrolment was more
remarkable—enrolment more than quadrupled between 1891 and 1941 with more than 6
per cent of school-age children attending secondary school by 1941.
However,
these enrolment levels mask the tremendous regional heterogeneity within
India. At
every level, the more advanced coastal provinces of Bengal, Bombay and Madras
out-performed the interior provinces of Bihar and United Provinces. Tremendous
variation across social groups was also evident: Certain religions such as
Christians and Jains were among the most literate in colonial India. At the
other end of the spectrum, tribal groups living in geographically remote parts
of the country had the lowest literacy, less than one per cent. Average Muslim
literacy at 6.4 per cent was below Hindu literacy at 8.4 per cent, but there
were significant regional differences. Among Hindus, there were large
differences by caste—Brahmans at the upper end of the caste spectrum averaged 33
per cent, while depressed castes averaged 1.6 per cent.
Although
the British created a new system of education, public investments in education
were very small: Education accounted for a small share of the total budget
averaging 3.5 per cent between 1881 and 1941. Official reports suggest British
administrators were aware that spending was perhaps inadequate to meet the needs
of expanding basic education, but they were also very critical of more spending
leading to better outcomes. Official rhetoric often emphasised low demand as the
primary constraint on educational development. This position may reflect
colonial strategy to absolve the Indian government from any blame for the low
level of investment. On the other hand, Congress leaders and Indian nationalists
bemoaned the low public spending and advocated higher spending as the key to
better outcomes.
Using
a new district-level dataset on spending and literacy, I found that public
investments on primary education had a positive and significant effect on male
literacy. However, there were no similar effects on female literacy. Official
British opinion and Indian opinion were thus both partially correct: higher
public spending would have increased male literacy, but building more public
schools was not the answer to the severe and persistent problem of female
illiteracy. For any significant literacy gains across the population, the Indian
government needed to substantially increase public spending on education.
By
underinvesting in public education, colonial rule did constrain the development
of primary education in India. But, this does not imply India would have enjoyed
better outcomes as an independent state. If anything, the slow progress after
1947 underscores that inadequate funding was not the only problem. The presence
of numerous castes and religions combined with the hierarchal divisions in
Indian society seriously undermined private and public attempts to expand basic
education.
Indian
elites, defined by caste, wealth and occupation, were among the chief
beneficiaries of English education. But, many of these same elites actively
blocked schemes for public expansion of primary schooling. Landed elites were
reluctant to support public education because they had to bear a
disproportionate cost in terms of land taxes, the main source of local revenues
for public primary schools. Educated elites belonging to the new urban
intelligentsia were unlikely to promote mass education because it would increase
competition for the much sought after Indian government jobs. Such resistance
frequently occurred at different levels of government, either through the
actions of local boards where landed and educated elites were disproportionately
represented, or through direct lobbying of colonial officials.
The
effects of caste and religious heterogeneity were even worse in the private
sector because the government had limited control over private schools, even
those that received public subsidies. Brahmans and other educated upper castes
successfully directed private and, to a smaller extent, public resources to
secondary schools for their children. Districts with a greater share of Brahmans
had more public and private secondary schools plus a smaller ratio of primary to
secondary schools. Districts with high levels of caste and religious diversity
had fewer private primary schools and a smaller ratio of primary to secondary
schools. However, upper castes were unable to completely co-opt the public
policymaking process because districts with larger proportions of lower castes
and Muslims also had more public secondary schools.
Official
attempts to circumvent the local politics of school provision were not
particularly effective at increasing literacy. In addition to caste problems, a
heavy reliance on religious schools hurt the progress of Muslim literacy.
Muslims in heavily Muslim-dominant districts had worse literacy because they had
experienced a more recent collapse of Muslim political authority and hence had
more powerful and better funded religious authorities. The religious authorities
established religious schools, which were less effective at promoting literacy
on the margin than public schools.
Colonial
policies did not do much to ameliorate these long-standing inequalities between
groups. Public spending was too low and susceptible to elite capture at many
levels. Given the lack of emphasis on human capital development, it would appear
that education was an important constraint on economic growth in colonial
India.