A Brief Colonial History Of Ceylon(SriLanka)
Sri Lanka: One Island Two Nations
A Brief Colonial History Of Ceylon(SriLanka)
Sri Lanka: One Island Two Nations
(Full Story)
Search This Blog
Back to 500BC.
==========================
Thiranjala Weerasinghe sj.- One Island Two Nations
?????????????????????????????????????????????????Wednesday, June 1, 2016
Referendum:Decision under Uncertainty
(Emeritus Professor of Economics,The University, Bangor, Wales, UK)
The referendum on British exit from the European Union is a symptom of
the rise of the politics of identity over the politics of prosperity.
Both sides in this debate have made forecasts of the economic outcome.
Forecasting organisations, barring a couple of dissenters, have
expressed fears of a sharp decline in the economy, at least in the short
run, if the Brexit camp wins. The Brexit camp counters these gloomy
forecasts arguing that the economy would adjust to a new pattern of
trade in no time and enter into a new era of prosperity by leaving the
EU. In any event, these arguments about economic forecasts are simply a
distraction for those that wish to leave. The Brexit camp places greater
store on sovereignty -- taking control over the legal definition of
human rights, dispensing with much of the regulations governing commerce
and industry, and setting rules for immigration. Once the vote is cast
to leave, there is no point of return. The decision criterion of
minimising the maximum potential disruption to the economy is the only
rational choice given the impossibility of computing the probabilities
of predicted consequences of the outcome of the vote. This criterion
favours a vote to remain a member.
We know what it is to live with membership, and we have some idea about
the likely success of agitating for change to make institution within
the UK and also in the EU more responsive to the voter. Institutions of
governance are always under the scanner in a democracy. Within the UK,
composition and selection rules of the upper chamber and devolution of
power between regions is not a settled matter. Likewise, the question of
democratic legitimacy of distribution of powers amongst various
institutions within the EU is being debated, and not just in the UK. In a
pluralistic democracy, not all citizens wish to subscribe to the same
agenda for change, and even an encompassing view which might emerge
would remain under scrutiny. A referendum is not the best way to
proceed.
A difference between parliamentary elections in a system of
representative government and voting in referenda is that the voter
imposes on herself and the rest of society a greater burden of any
unintended and unwelcome consequence of the outcome. This is especially
so when the status quo is severely jolted in pursuit of ideas which
cannot be measured in terms of their impact on our living standard.
In electing representatives to govern, the voter has the luxury of
voting for government on a policy platform, but judging the government
on consequences of that policy. Casting a vote for candidates
expounding, for example, a tough stance on immigration does not
constrain the voter from criticising a government thus elected if food
prices rise in consequence or if the availability of medical care is
compromised due to lack of qualified staff.
Mrs Thatcher secured a parliamentary majority in 1979 on a policy
platform comprising, inter alia, a vow dramatically to reduce the share
of government expenditure in the GDP. The ratio had climbed to 45 per
cent. Notwithstanding this harsh rhetoric, government expenditure and
its share in the GDP continued to increase in the initial years driven
by unforeseen fiscal pressure of a sudden and sharp rise in
unemployment. The ratio finally came down, but only to 40 per cent of
the GDP, when she left office a decade later.
This is not to say that representative governance entails cavalier
disregard of promises made at election but to suggest that the promises
need to be interpreted in context. The context is the need for elected
representatives to engage with complex technical issues and tedious
details of policy coherence once in government to avoid chaos.
Those that have voted for a government which commands a parliamentary
majority by expounding policies which appeal to the voters’ gut feelings
have the option of defeating the government in the next election if the
outcomes of following these policies turn out to be unappealing. This
paradox is understood by representatives and they moderate in
application promises made at election.
Governance by referenda, where policies are prescribed by the
electorate, is a different matter altogether. Unforeseen consequences
can be more disruptive in a referendum than in representative democracy.
That is why stable democracies choose representative forms of
government, and governance by referenda is shunned.
A textbook example of the disruptive nature of referendum politics is
the story, reported in the New York Times on the 5th of March 1995, of
the three strike sentencing referendum in California. A woman was
brutally murdered by a repeat offender recently released on parole after
a period in jail. In the background of emotive press reports, a
referendum was held on whether to mandate a harsh prison term of 25
years to life, without any possibility of parole before 20 years, for
all repeat offenders. Professionals engaged in the maintenance of law
and order advised against voting for a law imposing such an inflexible
mandate on the judiciary. The advice was ignored by a majority of the
electorate. Soon after the referendum was passed, a young pizza thief,
he was in the habit of going into restaurants eating a slice of pizza
and then escaping without paying, was sentenced to a term of 25 years to
life with no hope of parole before 20 years. Even those that had voted
for the referendum mandating this harsh punishment were aghast. The law
was eventually repealed but not before causing disruption to the
criminal justice system.
The ensuing referendum on continuing British membership of the European
Union is an exercise in making decisions under uncertainty. Whilst the
referendum ballot provides a binary choice, whether to remain in or to
exit from the EU, the voter is not faced with a binary decision. There
are multi-dimensional effects of the decision. The protagonists have
forecast vastly different consequences for British trade and prosperity
and also for world peace. They seldom emphasise that the probabilities
of potential outcomes of the vote for economics can only be assigned
subjectively. In our view, even the assignment of subjective
probabilities requires knowledge of the unknowable, and the best course
of action is to minimise the potential for maximum harm. That is to
stick to what we know and shun the temptation to take an irreversible
plunge into the unknown that is also unknowable.
Britain is a trading nation where international trade counts for
slightly less than a third of its GDP. Roughly half of that, 45 per cent
to be precise, is trade with the EU. The EU aspires to a single market
which entails companies being able to compete for government contracts
across frontiers within the EU without discrimination.
Those in favour of withdrawing from EU membership discount the prospect
of any adverse effect on British trade. Their argument is four-fold.
Firstly, they assert that access to European markets could be swiftly
negotiated without necessarily having to comply with the rules for free
movement of labour within the EU and without having to follow EU
directives specifying, for example, labour rights at work and
environmental conditions in production. A second line of argument is
that it does not matter if negotiations stall. Any adverse consequences
of disruption to trade with the EU could be ameliorated through
improving trade relations with countries outside the Europe. This
assumption is oblivious of the fact that the leaders of some of the
largest economies outside the Europe with whom the Brexit camp aspires
to increase trade have advised against British departure from the EU. A
third line of argument derives from the belief that hitherto untapped
energies would be unleashed in the British economy freed from EU
regulations. A fourth line of argument from Brexit, put forward by some
in the left, is a modified version of the above. It is the EU
bureaucracy which holds back the ability of a British government to
determine for itself policies on selective subsidy to make the economy
flourish. Some in the Brexit camp would be prepared to accept a
reduction in prosperity to get back sovereignty, but leaders campaigning
for leaving the EU, on the whole, do not accept the premise of a trade
off between sovereignty and prosperity.
(To be continued tomorrow)