A Brief Colonial History Of Ceylon(SriLanka)
Sri Lanka: One Island Two Nations
A Brief Colonial History Of Ceylon(SriLanka)
Sri Lanka: One Island Two Nations
(Full Story)
Search This Blog
Back to 500BC.
==========================
Thiranjala Weerasinghe sj.- One Island Two Nations
?????????????????????????????????????????????????Monday, October 3, 2016
Reorganising the electricity supply industry
Part III: Peering into a technically rational crystal ball
This concluding third part of the series outlines a conceptual proposal
for the reorganisation of the electricity supply industry (ESI) in
Lanka; it is conceptual, not a blueprint cast in stone. The motive is to
embrace new technologies and business practices and to meet emerging
challenges. Privatisation is inimical when national or regional monopoly
settings (‘public goods’) prevail – transmission ownership, operation
and system control is an example; similar functions in distribution are
another example. Only a lunatic will contemplate two overlapping
transmission systems in one country or imagine two distribution networks
under roads and over farms and homes in a locality.
Where competition is desirable is in electricity generation. An IPP
(Independent Power producer) may be domestic, foreign (FDI) or
joint-venture capital. There was a global trend towards a power market
in the 1990s but after the catastrophic California Power Market crash in
2001 the trend receded. Globally, recent acquisitions signal a turn to
consolidation, but irrespective of market type, the ESI is responding to
advances in technology and new options in energy supply. Global
fashions however must be modified to a local context; otherwise one will
be shooting at abstract targets.
Smaller gas-fired plants are cost competitive in capital and operation
in countries with gas deposits. This makes distributed generation
attractive. But in Lanka this is predicated on a gas distribution
network for industry and transport in general; otherwise better stay
with centralised power stations and ship out electricity. In a trade-off
between transmission losses and capital investment in special purpose
pipelines to ship gas to power stations only, the former wins.
Mini and micro generation (less than 10MW; hydro, wind, rooftop PV and
wood based) and industry based standby plant is on the increase, but
electricity sector reorganisation is not warranted to deal with these
pimples. Rooftop solar (as distinct from large utility size solar farms)
even if it adds hundreds of MW of simultaneous injection at high-noon
on a bright day, can, technically, be handled on-the-hop by distribution
entities.
Independence of the system operator-cum-transmission-owner, and
independence of a centralised electricity buyer from individual
generating companies (including the CEB’s generation arm) is imperative
if competition in power supply and the incorporation of large solar (and
wind) farms is to be accomplished. Sounds complicated? Hang on; it will
be clearer when a typical structure is laid out, so let me take the
plunge and sketch a long-term structure; it is premature to discuss
implementation stages. The diagram shows functions that currently belong
to the CEB split into three blocks - CEGen, CEGrid & CEBuy and
Discos. Separate from this is Other Generators, Consumers, the Regulator
(a replacement PUCL) and Contracts. Let me lay out the thinking behind
this.
The independent grid operator
The transmission system - and its control, management and expansion - is
queen of electricity supply. CEGrid must be impartial to all competing
suppliers in the market, including CEB generation (CEGen); it must be
even-handed to all buyers (Discos). Above all as a national monopoly -
provider of a public good - it must be a publicly accountable body like
the Central Bank. Think of CEGrid as a court of law adjudicating between
plaintiffs (generators) and defendants (distributors).
To achieve these ends it must be independent of all generators and
distributors and tracked by a sensible rule-making Regulator. (Currently
PUCL and CEB are involved in a procession of petty squabbles; "We told
you to do a 20-year plan, how dare you do a 24-year plan!") . CEGrid
will impose a use-of-system fee on generators and end-users to recoup
transmission losses and organisation costs and to procure funds for grid
expansion. The principal structural change that I am emphasising today,
an independent transmission entity (CEGrid), is already well
established in quite a few countries.
CEGrid can contemplate many innovations. One overhyped novelty is the
so-called smart-grid. This is the use of computer intelligence,
power-electronic switches, algorithms and the Internet to re-switch
lines and devices called SVCs and capacitors so as to enhance
operational capability. At least that’s the hype, but I am not convinced
that the smart-grid is a game changer or has achieved much in
transmission networks. (Distribution is another story; automation and
smart techniques have improved reliability between the consumer and the
local supply point in many countries). Of course many things can be done
without restructuring, but the point is not in the detail; it is that
the grid must be free to improve, innovate, keep abreast of developments
and not be tied to the apron strings of any power generation company or
corporation. For example there has been talk of an up to date system
control centre for years, but little has happened. An independent CEGrid
will be more motivated and have its own budget; "unbundling" or
separation is a concept that deserves scrutiny by stakeholders.
Competition in generation
The big story globally in the 1990s was competition in generation to
bring down prices and enhance efficiency. To prepare the ground locally,
the generation arm of the CEB will have to be spun off into a separate
state-owned entity, CEGen. Or maybe two; a hydro part and a thermal
generator like India’s state owned National Thermal Power Corporation,
India’s largest power producer. The hydro sector in Lanka has a unique
feature; fuel cost is zero but dispatch (water discharge schedules) must
respect downstream irrigation and human needs. This imposes constraints
on ‘dispatch’ - ‘dispatch’ means running generators and injecting power
into the grid.
Reliance, Tata and other mega-players have entered the Indian power
market and compete for market share. It is similar in other big
countries. But if a truly competitive market is opened in Lanka will
there be IPP takers? I am not sure whether IPPs in Lanka only want
protected sinecures. Note that competition is not to be confused with
the money for jam game that IPPs have been played in this country for 20
years. Fat profits, recovery of investment and guaranteed sales is not
risk taking competition. Nevertheless let’s put my doubts to one side
and assume that the private sector will respond to a power market,
investing in the sector and competing genuinely on the basis of price.
Where will future gas-fired power stations fed from an LNG harbour
terminal fit in? I guess construction of the $500 million LNG terminal
will be venture between a port authority and foreign capital. Long term
ownership will presumably be vested in some state entity because not
only power generators but transport and industry will need to access it.
We can then conjecture that from say 2025 power growth will average
about a 300MW year. The technologies of choice will be gas, clean coal
if its reputation is restored, and renewables. Let us conjecture that
some of this is undertaken by CEGen but that private developers too will
respond. This then is the case for a competitive power market.
CEGen, even stripped of the hydro component will be a pretty profitable
enterprise; it could be profitable right now if shorn of the burden of
providing subsidised electricity to indigent sections of the population
and religious places. In a competitive power market, subsidies are a
societal choice to be met by government, not burdened on a generator.
CEGen will be able to drive competitors out of the market since the
biggest component of cost, pass-through fuel cost (gas price), will be
the same for all. But CEGen has a head start with Norochcholi, whose
coal based prices, gas-fired plants will not be able to match - see
tables in last week’s Part II.
CEBuy
CEBuy is mostly bits-and-bytes; in manpower and capital it will be a
small unit whose job is to clear the market. That is, it will, with the
assistance of the Discos, post data and its own expertise, forecast
day-ahead demand in say half-hourly time steps for the next day. It will
also receive on-line, offers of how much power and at what prices,
competing generators are offering. It then clears the market; that is it
accepts the cheapest offers for each time step, notifies these
generators and informs CEGrid what to expect. Tough luck for generators
who quote high though most may be able to sell something at peak time.
Buy and Grid must coordinate intimately since dispatch schedules
submitted by Buy may be operationally infeasible, making regular
iteration necessary.
Real-time demand and day-ahead dispatch schedules will not match
exactly, or there will be unexpected events. CEGrid will therefore have
‘balancing power’ agreements with some generators to buy or shed extra
power at a moment’s notice. CEGrid may even own some fast acting
generators. In my view a better option is to vest control of the hydro
complexes (Mahaweli, Kelani, Walawe etc.) in CEGrid. These zero-cost
units are not relevant to competition, water storage is vital to both
long term irrigation and power dispatch planning, and daily/weekly
running of hydro is constrained by downstream needs. The logical place
for all this is an energy management sub-unit of CEGrid.
Solar power has a random quality that requires intimate operational
alignment with CEGrid. One rationale for disentangling CEGrid into a
separate entity is to deal with solar power’s headaches (stochastic,
non-dispatchable and without inertia – see Part I). If renewables are
going to come in big time, then an independent system control and
dispatch entity is useful. You will observe that my case for
restructuring is not much based on competition in generation but much
more to do with technical rationalities that can be incorporated if
CEGrid is independent from CEGen. A further motive for restructuring is
that there may be a good case for introducing Discos – next section.
If the power market does not take off Buy can be dismantled and absorbed
into Grid leaving a simple three tier structure of a statutorily
independent grid which also looks after hydro, a state owned thermal
power generator and several regional distributors. It is absolutely
essential that the structure, at least at the early stages, be kept
simple. Complication will lead to chaos!
I crave your indulgence to address a few words of technical gibberish to
engineer readers. I believe fixed frequency AC will remain the
foundation of electricity supply for the remainder of this century.
Nicola Tesla’s marvellous transformer cannot be supplanted. Then,
massive rotating masses will remain the bedrock of frequency and
stability management. Photovoltaics and technologies which generate DC
and inject power through inverters (power electronic devices) will play a
supplementary role, but the AC grid will reign supreme. This essay on
ESI restructuring adopts this as a premise.
Discos
Currently CEB distribution is managed by nationwide regional
distribution divisions and one semi-independent company LECO. At some
point in time maybe we should spin-off this family into many LECO-like
independent entities. Since electricity distribution is a regional
monopoly (a public good) these entities will have to be regulated and
accountable to the public. Since LECO seems to be a success there may be
economies and efficiencies of dis-scale in unbundling. On the other
hand economies of scale may be lost. Prima face assumptions may prove
wrong; why not start with one or two more distant trials (Jaffna
Peninsula, Upcountry, Matara and beyond) and see what experience
teaches.
I cannot discuss the Regulator (PUSL has to be reformatted if the
electricity supply industry is restructured) or explain the box called
Contracts on the right because this piece will become longer; I have
overrun my usual word limit already. In closing I repeat, my
prescriptions are flexible; they are an invitation to further
discussion.
(The author’s IEEE Fellowship was for work on ESI Restructuring)