A Brief Colonial History Of Ceylon(SriLanka)
Sri Lanka: One Island Two Nations
A Brief Colonial History Of Ceylon(SriLanka)
Sri Lanka: One Island Two Nations
(Full Story)
Search This Blog
Back to 500BC.
==========================
Thiranjala Weerasinghe sj.- One Island Two Nations
?????????????????????????????????????????????????Sunday, February 26, 2017
But that’s no reason for governments to stop supporting them
ALMOST 150 years after photovoltaic cells and wind turbines were
invented, they still generate only 7% of the world’s electricity. Yet
something remarkable is happening. From being peripheral to the energy
system just over a decade ago, they are now growing faster than any
other energy source and their falling costs are making them competitive
with fossil fuels. BP, an oil firm, expects renewables to account for
half of the growth in global energy supply over the next 20 years. It is
no longer far-fetched to think that the world is entering an era of
clean, unlimited and cheap power. About time, too.
There is a $20trn hitch, though. To get from here to there requires huge
amounts of investment over the next few decades, to replace old
smog-belching power plants and to upgrade the pylons and wires that
bring electricity to consumers. Normally investors like putting their
money into electricity because it offers reliable returns. Yet green
energy has a dirty secret. The more it is deployed, the more it lowers
the price of power from any source. That makes it hard to manage the
transition to a carbon-free future, during which many generating
technologies, clean and dirty, need to remain profitable if the lights
are to stay on. Unless the market is fixed, subsidies to the industry
will only grow.
Policymakers are already seeing this inconvenient truth as a reason to
put the brakes on renewable energy. In parts of Europe and China,
investment in renewables is slowing as subsidies are cut back. However,
the solution is not less wind and solar. It is to rethink how the world
prices clean energy in order to make better use of it.
Shock to the system
At its heart, the problem is that government-supported renewable energy
has been imposed on a market designed in a different era. For much of
the 20th century, electricity was made and moved by vertically
integrated, state-controlled monopolies. From the 1980s onwards, many of
these were broken up, privatised and liberalised, so that market forces
could determine where best to invest. Today only about 6% of
electricity users get their power from monopolies. Yet everywhere the
pressure to decarbonise power supply has brought the state creeping back
into markets. This is disruptive for three reasons. The first is the
subsidy system itself. The other two are inherent to the nature of wind
and solar: their intermittency and their very low running costs. All
three help explain why power prices are low and public subsidies are
addictive.
First, the splurge of public subsidy, of about $800bn since 2008, has
distorted the market. It came about for noble reasons—to counter climate
change and prime the pump for new, costly technologies, including wind
turbines and solar panels. But subsidies hit just as electricity
consumption in the rich world was stagnating because of growing energy
efficiency and the financial crisis. The result was a glut of
power-generating capacity that has slashed the revenues utilities earn
from wholesale power markets and hence deterred investment.
Second, green power is intermittent. The vagaries of wind and
sun—especially in countries without favourable weather—mean that
turbines and solar panels generate electricity only part of the time. To
keep power flowing, the system relies on conventional power plants,
such as coal, gas or nuclear, to kick in when renewables falter. But
because they are idle for long periods, they find it harder to attract
private investors. So, to keep the lights on, they require public funds.
Everyone is affected by a third factor: renewable energy has negligible
or zero marginal running costs—because the wind and the sun are free. In
a market that prefers energy produced at the lowest short-term cost,
wind and solar take business from providers that are more expensive to
run, such as coal plants, depressing power prices, and hence revenues
for all.
Get smart
The higher the penetration of renewables, the worse these problems
get—especially in saturated markets. In Europe, which was first to feel
the effects, utilities have suffered a “lost decade” of falling returns,
stranded assets and corporate disruption. Last year, Germany’s two
biggest electricity providers, E.ON and RWE, both split in two. In
renewable-rich parts of America power providers struggle to find
investors for new plants. Places with an abundance of wind, such as
China, are curtailing wind farms to keep coal plants in business.
The corollary is that the electricity system is being re-regulated as
investment goes chiefly to areas that benefit from public support.
Paradoxically, that means the more states support renewables, the more
they pay for conventional power plants, too, using “capacity payments”
to alleviate intermittency. In effect, politicians rather than markets
are once again deciding how to avoid blackouts. They often make
mistakes: Germany’s support for cheap, dirty lignite caused emissions to
rise, notwithstanding huge subsidies for renewables. Without a new
approach the renewables revolution will stall.
The good news is that new technology can help fix the problem (see article).
Digitalisation, smart meters and batteries are enabling companies and
households to smooth out their demand—by doing some energy-intensive
work at night, for example. This helps to cope with intermittent supply.
Small, modular power plants, which are easy to flex up or down, are
becoming more popular, as are high-voltage grids that can move excess
power around the network more efficiently.
The bigger task is to redesign power markets to reflect the new need for
flexible supply and demand. They should adjust prices more frequently,
to reflect the fluctuations of the weather. At times of extreme
scarcity, a high fixed price could kick in to prevent blackouts. Markets
should reward those willing to use less electricity to balance the
grid, just as they reward those who generate more of it. Bills could be
structured to be higher or lower depending how strongly a customer
wanted guaranteed power all the time—a bit like an insurance policy. In
short, policymakers should be clear they have a problem and that the
cause is not renewable energy, but the out-of-date system of electricity
pricing. Then they should fix it.